21 research outputs found

    Concentration in Hungarian Food Retailing and Supplier-Retailer Relationships

    Get PDF
    The paper is a summary about the Hungarian retail sector based on the results of different research projects completed in the last five years. From all of these studies and of course the wide ranging domestic and international literature we had to conclude that the retailers have become more and more the exclusive owner of the information about the consumers and with this they become the new "captains" of the food chain. Thus we always started our research with gathering information about the situation of the Hungarian retail sector because we believed if we want to help those who try to adapt (the suppliers) then we have to know much more about those who dictate (the retailers). Analysing the concentration in company and not branch level we can say that the cumulated concentration line of the CR-10 companies are very similar to that of the processing and the retail sector. But there is a very important difference in the absolute numbers. This is a further sign of the size and power difference in favour of retailing.food retailing, concentration, market structure, supplier-retailer relationships, Industrial Organization, D3, L81,

    The impact of labels on the competitiveness of the European food label supply chain

    Get PDF
    The report studies the impact of private labels on the competitiveness of the European food processing industry and investigates whether a system of producer indication may improve the functioning of the food supply chain. The impact is studied using economic theory and empirical and legal analysis. The study is completed with an impact assessment

    GMAP is an Atg8a-interacting protein that regulates Golgi turnover In Drosophila

    Get PDF
    Selective autophagy receptors and adapters contain short linear motifs called LIR motifs (LC3-interacting region), which are required for the interaction with the Atg8-family proteins. LIR motifs bind to the hydrophobic pockets of the LIR motif docking site (LDS) of the respective Atg8-family proteins. The physiological significance of LDS docking sites has not been clarified in vivo. Here, we show that Atg8a-LDS mutant Drosophila flies accumulate autophagy substrates and have reduced lifespan. Using quantitative proteomics to identify the proteins that accumulate in Atg8a-LDS mutants, we identify the cis-Golgi protein GMAP (Golgi microtubule-associated protein) as a LIR motif-containing protein that interacts with Atg8a. GMAP LIR mutant flies exhibit accumulation of Golgi markers and elongated Golgi morphology. Our data suggest that GMAP mediates the turnover of Golgi by selective autophagy to regulate its morphology and size via its LIR motif-mediated interaction with Atg8a

    How Effective is the Invisible Hand? Agricultural and Food Markets in Central and Eastern Europe

    Get PDF
    Since the seminal work of Adam Smith, markets have been considered an efficient tool for co-ordinating the behaviour of economic agents. The basic characteristic of a market economy is that the complex system of interaction among individuals is not centrally coordinated. Under the assumption of profit and utility maximisation (and a whole set of assumptions about the institutional framework), relative prices and their change over time provide the signals that guide, like an invisible hand, the allocation of resources, i.e., the structure of production and the intensity of input use in the various production processes. They do this by co-ordinating the activities of economic agents, i.e., of resource owners, producers, intermediaries, traders, and consumers. After system change in the former Soviet Union and in Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) central economic planning had to be replaced by other forms of co-ordination. The general direction in all transition countries was towards a market economy, but the speed and depth of reforms towards an environment in which markets can evolve differed largely between countries, sectors and between different phases during the past 15 years. IAMO Forum 2005 focuses on this development and discusses the functioning of markets, the requirements for this, and the advantages and disadvantages of other co-ordination mechanisms under different environments in the agricultural and food sectors in Central and Eastern Europe. CEE agri-food markets deserve researchers' and policy makers' attention for several reasons. Two of them regard the high demand for support to policy decisions that aim to stimulate economic and social development in the region. In most CEE countries, the significance of the agricultural and food sector is relatively high with respect to income and employment. In particular, rural areas can benefit from the development of this branch of the economy. Also, there is marked indication that agri-food markets in CEE are not ensuring exchange as frictionless as possible. This means that large benefits can be expected if potential improvements of the economic environment are implemented and if individual agents adapt optimally to that environment. Another motivation for economic research on transition countries is that we are looking at a huge region that started almost as a vacuum with regard to institutional settings. This means that a wide range of substantially different settings were introduced in the respective countries, and were only weakly confined by political rigidities or path dependencies. From a distant perspective, the repeated fundamental shifts in recent economic policies almost evoke the impression of a trial and error approach. The consequences of distinctively different options (across countries and periods) can be observed in a way almost similar to a laboratory situation. Such unique opportunity has attracted economists, particularly those interested in institutional economics, to conduct research on CEE. However, this also means that the experiences made in CEEC can enhance the general understanding of what markets can do and what the limitations of market coordination are. This volume contains selected contributions presented at IAMO Forum 2005 and gives an overview of the major topics discussed there. Partial analyses of specific economic problems usually abstract from the general economic framework which is assumed to be more or less constant as expressed in ceteris paribus clauses. Oftentimes, the set of institutional conditions is even assumed to be sufficiently well-described by the framework used in neoclassical models. Particularly for transition countries, this has frequently led to spurious results because crucial aspects of the framework actually in place were not considered, and sometimes were not even thought of. An extreme and very obvious example is the neglect of the effects of the replacement of monetary by nonmonetary exchange in phases of a barter economy. There is no generic approach to avoid unintended omission of crucial framework conditions, but it must generally be emphasised that a broad look at the various interdependent markets and at the entire socioeconomic context of a country is needed before going into detail. Descriptive analyses of the situation in various markets form part of such a broad look. The contributions of POPP, FERTÃ et al., WILKIN et al., and HEIN in the chapter Selected analyses from CEEC provide excellent examples, and focus on market developments in new EU member countries. On the one hand, the papers show the heterogeneity of problems e.g. due to largely differing farm structures. On the other hand, several common patterns can be observed: The market shares and power of large processors and retailers (hypermarkets, etc.) are increasing. Also, international (especially intra-EU) trade in commodities has increased in response to CAP-induced price harmonisation. Both tendencies weaken the market position of farmers, particularly small entities which cannot supply in volumes sufficient for large processing and trade firms. Within the food industry concentration increased as many smaller firms could not comply with EU processing standards and had to quit the market. The increased size and specialization of large producers, as well as of large processors, made many of those firms co-ordinate business with each other through long-term contractual agreements rather than by relying on spot markets. This tendency is very distinct in the fruit and vegetable sector, as WILKINâs contribution describes. Two contributions draw attention to the institutional framework itself, mainly by looking at circumstances which prevent market allocation from leading to an optimal outcome. HOBBS describes factors that impede investment and growth by drawing on transaction cost economics. Situations typical for transition countries are highlighted where e.g. transparency is not sufficient or the existence and reliable enforcement of contract or corporate law are not guaranteed. NUPPENAU stresses the need for the appropriate and precise formulation of land property rights, which should evoke a balance between governance and exclusion. The importance of appropriate and reliable institutions to avoid flaws is emphasised. But even with suitable institutions, transaction costs cannot be reduced to zero. The main reason for this is that since agents may gain form a head start of information, incentives to reveal their knowledge are quite restricted. Furthermore, some of the information required to make correct decisions is not available. This especially concerns information regarding all future contingencies. An uncertain future and the asymmetric distribution of information impose special problems when decisions have long-term effects and agents are linked together through investment decisions. This offers possibilities for opportunistic behaviour, i.e., when an agent behaves in a way that allows him to extract rents from the partners' activities. The friction induced in such situations may result in a market outcome that is biased by transaction costs. Mitigating this bias should be a goal of public policy but it is also in the interest of (at least some of the) private agents involved. This issue is discussed in more detail in the papers dealing with alternative governance structures. A number of contributions to IAMO Forum highlight approaches for measuring the well-functioning of markets. While studies that aim to directly measure transaction costs are very rare and are necessarily limited to comparing only very specific portions of transaction costs, most studies focus on indirect indicators. These usually start from the idea that in a well-functioning, competitive market any supply or demand shocks are reflected in price changes, not only in the particular market where the shock occurs but also in other, related markets, i.e., in different locations or at different stages of the production and marketing chain. Consequently, an approach for assessing the functioning of markets is to compare price differentials with processing-, marketing- or transfer-costs, or â since these costs are usually difficult to quantify â to observe price differentials over time. Accepting the assumption that the costs reflected by price differentials are more or less constant (or stationary) over the observed time span, any additional price changes or a lack of price co-movement is interpreted as an indication for insufficiently connected or insufficiently functioning markets. Three contributions in the chapter Analytical approaches for measuring market efficiency describe analyses which mainly focus on the vertical dimension, i.e., between market stages. BOJNEC, in his descriptive price analysis for several agricultural products in Slovenia since 1991, finds a heterogeneous development of the farm gate/consumer price spread: The processing and marketing margins increased for wheat and beef while they declined for grapes (processed to wine), sugar and poultry. BRÃMMER and ZORYA, as well as BAKUCS and FERTÃ, use cointegration analysis to describe the degree and nature of vertical price integration in the Ukrainian wheat market and the Hungarian pork market, respectively. Both studies find that price changes are transmitted vertically, that there is a tendency to "correct" any deviations from some underlying equilibrium price-relationship. However, such error correction mechanisms are found not to be a constant, universal force. In the Hungarian paper, it could only be found for a sub-period of the observed time span, excluding the highly volatile early 1990s. Also, equilibrium was found to be achieved by adjustment of farm gate prices only while the retail prices were found to be exogenous, i.e., not responding to any disequilibrium. The paper on Ukraine shows that adjustment processes between wheat and wheat flour prices cannot be sufficiently described by a constant error correction mechanism for the period 2000 to 2004. In fact, four different regimes of adjustment processes were found to have been in force, reflecting particular phases of largely differing market situations and political interventions. The functioning of markets depends on several crucial conditions. One of these conditions concerns the availability of information. Only if agents have perfect and complete information will the exchange lead to an outcome in which no individual can be better off without reducing the welfare of others. However, in the real world this condition regarding information is not fulfilled. Information is not perfect, since the future cannot be predicted with certainty. Incomplete information results from, first, not all information being revealed, and second, individuals not possessing the mental capacity to collect and process all information. Moreover, because of its asymmetric distribution, information can be regarded as a resource that can be exploited by agents. This means that there are incentives to hamper the diffusion of information to the public domain. In general, the more uncertain the future is and the more information is tacit, the worse markets will function, and the more beneficial become alternative mechanisms of coordination. Three papers dealing with this issue of organisational choice. HANF focuses on governance structures within supply chain networks that are appropriate for allowing an optimal flow of information between the involved individuals while retaining the necessary hierarchy for efficient implementation of strategic decisions. MAACKâs analysis shows that there is strong mutual interest between producers and processors of berry fruits to reduce marketing and procurement risk, respectively. This can be achieved by switching from spot market exchange to contractual supply agreements. A prerequisite for such agreements is that a well-balanced distribution of risks and risk premiums between the farmer and processor is implemented. This means that processors, who â facing a multitude of small producers â are used to opportunities for exerting market power, have to agree to cover part of the production risk through appropriate contractual clauses. Finally, BALINT looks at the various marketing channels used by Romanian farmers and finds that a self-enforcing dualism exists. For commercially-oriented farmers who can supply large quantities, marketing directly to traders, wholesalers and processors is most favourable and involves relatively low transaction costs. Although this form of supply-relationship is usually not based on contractual agreements, it can still be characterised by a certain stability over time. In contrast, small farmers whose production does not considerably exceed the subsistence level incur relatively high (per unit) transaction costs in selling their produce on local markets and to other farmers. Another aspect of organisational choice is the question of whether ownership of production factors is transferred or only the right to use them temporarily. The uncertainty of future developments implies that the possession of resources cannot be only regarded from the point of view of income generation at a certain point in time. With perfect foresight, there is no difference whether a factor is rented or purchased, because the remuneration would be the same. This perfect substitutability is no longer given when the future is uncertain. Income generation, then, is only one feature of ownership. Additional aspects such as insurance, wealth, and speculation as motivations for possession affect the value of ownership and thus shift the demand and supply curves of the factor. HURRELMAN picks up this issue in her analysis of the Polish land market and shows the impact of additional grounds for valuing property on the decision to rent or to buy land. Uncertainty may also affect the specialization of factor use. Allocating a factor of production to different production activities reduces the risk of income instabilities, but at the cost of specialization gains through economics of scale. Moreover, the decision on income combination is â besides risk â affected by a complex interaction of other determinants. GLAUBEN et al., analyse these interactions for the case of part-time farming in China and show how the decision of income combination is affected by household characteristics, human capital and other variables. Incomplete and imperfect information not only causes individuals to choose optimal governance modes, often it is also understood as a call for government intervention. The selected papers in the chapter on policy intervention plead for careful selection and coherent implementation of policy instruments. BENNER, as well as KUHN, highlight the significance of information diffusion and argue in favour of government intervention in this area. However, both emphasise that these interferences should be used carefully and be adjusted to specific market failures. Both argue that setting up information systems would improve the functioning of markets. BENNER also discusses possible negative impacts if governments that engage in setting up and enforcing product and process standards try, at the same time, to foster a sector like agriculture through support in marketing. The latter activity affects the governmentâs (crucial) credibility in the first activity. KUHN points to negative welfare effects and budgetary requirements of an intervention system which is implemented to increase price stability. Moreover, when a government intervenes in market allocation or intends to provide rules that should facilitate the exchange on markets, it has to take into account that the new regulation has to be implemented in a coherent manner. This requires the various policy regulations and institutional settings to be complementary and not cause frictions which hamper the functioning of the system. LERMAN and SHAGAIDA highlight this aspect in their discussion of the Russian land market, where bureaucracy and high costs for the registration of property rights can be regarded as a major cause of the low number of land transactions. However, since economic activities take place in a dynamic environment, the comparative static point of view may lead to inappropriate policy formulation. WANDEL discusses this aspect in the context of competition policy. From a comparative static point of view, market power has to be assessed negatively because of the distortions of resource allocation. However, monopoly profits are an indicator of extra rents and thus provide incentives for market entry. On the one hand, this thread may lead to special pricing schemes and/or to the accelerated development of technological change so that a monopolist can consolidate its market position. But it is possible, on the other hand, that market entry may in fact happen. In this case, one would observe structural change, which would be accompanied by an improved use of resources. This in turn means that competition policy should not be oriented towards an optimal market structure but towards the facilitation of market entry so that competition can discover market opportunities and determine the optimal structure of the market. The present volume shows the wide range of interesting and controversial topics that are concerned when looking at co-ordination, particularly on markets in CEE agri-food sectors. It remains a hope that the heterogeneity and dynamics of the developments will decrease as successful constellations of framework conditions, organisational choices and individual behaviour become more and more obvious and widespread in the region. Conversion to sustainable, balanced patterns might take place, but this cannot be taken for granted. However, chances for such development are better the more stable and balanced political developments, as well as international co-operation, become. We hope that the academic community will contribute towards such goal.Agribusiness, Community/Rural/Urban Development, Industrial Organization, International Development, Labor and Human Capital, Land Economics/Use, Political Economy,

    Horizon 2020 Societal Challenge 2 \u201cFood Security, Sustainable Agriculture and Forestry, Marine, Maritime and Inland Water Research, and the Bioeconomy\u201d Advisory Group Recommendations Programming Period 2018-2020

    Get PDF
    The Horizon 2020 Societal Challenge 2 Programme was created to develop and implement an EU research and innovation policy for more sustainable and resource efficient agriculture, forestry, inland water and marine systems that supply European society with sufficient food, feed, biomass, and other raw materials, as well as ecosystems services, and support thriving rural and coastal livelihoods. The European Commission has established Societal Challenge Advisory Groups to provide consistent and consolidated advice - by way of opinions, recommendations and reports - on relevant research objectives and scientific, technological and innovation priorities for its strategic and annual work programmes. Our Societal Challenge 2 Advisory Group includes a wide range of members with remarkably rich and diverse backgrounds and affiliations, including researchers, academics, former policymakers - stakeholders covering the whole spectrum of relevant research and innovation domains. Our Advisory Group has met twice formally since our establishment in February 2016, and has used other opportunities for extensive discussion and engagement on the issues surrounding this Societal Challenge. We see Societal Challenge 2 as not only extremely important as a challenge in itself, but also strongly linked with other Societal Challenges such as health, demographic change and wellbeing, climate action, environment, resource efficiency and raw materials, and inclusive, innovative and reflective societies in a changing world. And as the agriculture, forestry, fisheries and food sectors comprise a very large number of smaller businesses \u2013 themselves serving large scale processing and retail business sectors \u2013 there are strong links between our contribution and the input of groups advising on innovation in small and medium-sized enterprises, international cooperation, nanotechnologies, advanced materials and advanced manufacturing and processing. Our Advisory Group\u2018s first task has been to prepare this report to answer five specific questions posed by the Commission and provide input into the strategic programming cycle of the Work Programme for 2018-2020. We have identified some overriding strategic priorities, and backed those with the results of a more detailed analysis of the gaps that need to be addressed. And we highlight the cross-cutting nature of this programme and the importance of an integrated approach to maximise the overall impact of the current Horizon 2020 programme. We hope that the insights in this report may also assist in the identification and prioritisation of research needs and strengthen the Commission\u2018s strategic and impact-oriented approach in future years

    Az élelmiszerlánc szereplői közötti kapcsolatok hazánkban

    No full text
    Hazánkban a válság miatt a keresleti oldalról növekedni képtelen piacon a kiskereskedelmi szereplők a kötelező éves növekedést immár csak a piac újraosztásával érhetik el, ami a kiskereskedők között kíméletlen – horizontális – versenyt eredményez. Ennek eszköze az alapvető termékek esetében a minél alacsonyabban tartott ár. Ezért a kereskedelmi láncok és beszállítóik kapcsolata vegyes képet mutat. A nagy, tőkeerős, elsősorban nemzetközi élelmiszer-feldolgozók és mezőgazdasági beszállítók számára még így is jövedelmező lehet a kereskedelmi láncok által biztosított széles körű piaci jelenlét. Ezzel szemben a hazai szinten nagy, de nem elég tőkeerős hazai beszállítók alkupozíciója rendkívül kényes, számukra még veszteség mellett is létkérdés a kereskedelmi láncok nyújtotta piaci jelenlét, mivel az alternatív értékesítési csatornák egy részéhez túl nagyok (független boltok), más részéhez pedig túl kicsik (exportpiacok). Paradox módon tehát a hazai piaci viszonyok között az élelmiszer-gazdasági vállalkozások növekedése a közép-nagy vállalati határon komoly jövedelmezőségi és értékesítési gondokhoz vezet. Az EU tagállamaként Magyarországon a versenyjogot az uniós és a harmonizált hazai versenyjogi szabályok jelentik. Az agrárszektor specialitásait ezzel szemben a közös és a nemzeti agrárpolitika jeleníti meg, az ágazati szabályozás keretében elsőbbséget biztosítva a versenyjogi szabályok alkalmazásával szemben. Az élelmiszer termékpálya teljes kizárása a versenyszabályok alkalmazása alól azonban az uniós tagállami kötelezettségeink felmondását jelenti, ezért nem jogszerű megoldásról lenne szó. A piaci zavarok esetében az állam piacbefolyásoló, árakat is érintő ad hoc beavatkozásai nem képesek a piaci folyamatokat tartósan befolyásolni, sőt csökkentik a tartós megoldások kialakulásának esélyét is (legfeljebb az indulatok csillapítására alkalmasak). Joggal tehető fel akkor a kérdés, hogy a várhatóan továbbra is fennmaradó kíméletlenversenyben lehet és érdemes-e a hazai élelmiszer-gazdaság erodálódását, szelekcióját gátolni? Véleményünk szerint mindenképpen, de csak reális tisztánlátásra épülhetnek a hazai beszállítók számára kétségkívül kedvezőtlen piaci helyzet javításának valós és hatásos eszközei. A készülő Nemzeti Vidék Stratégia társadalmi vitája előtt így kiemelkedően fontosnak tartottuk, hogy az ellátási lánc szereplői között felhalmozódott feszültségek okait számba vegyük, valamint a közigazgatás beavatkozási lehetőségeiről kialakult tévhiteket eloszlassuk. ------------------------------- The food supply chain connects three important sectors – agriculture, the food processing industry and the distribution sectors. Key challenges identified for the food supply chain are the sub-optimal relationships between the stakeholders in the chain. Due to the large number of small and medium-sized companies, the food industry has an unequal bargaining power when compared to the highly concentrated retail sector. Even the largest food companies account for only 1-2% of a retailer’s business at national level, while a retailer may represent 20-30% of those companies’ businesses. The lack of market transparency, inequalities in bargaining power and anti-competitive practices have led to market distortions with negative effects on the competitiveness of the food supply chain as a whole. Asymmetry in bargaining power can lead to inefficiencies. Due to increased delays and asymmetry in price transmission, low comparability of retail prices, diversity of markets and actors along the chain, anticompetitive practices may potentially occur. As a result, food companies have a lower capacity to invest and innovate, and on the longer-term the economic welfare and choice of consumers is jeopardised. It important to exercise constant vigilance in order to identify and eliminate market distortions that have contributed to the observed asymmetries in price transmission along the food supply chain. While the food sector is in favour of strong competition, such unfair practices can only be solved be re-focusing the existing instruments of competition law. The issue of manifest unfair practices and the increasing buying power of retailers along the food chain has to be addressed. The rapid rise and fall of agricultural commodity prices and its delayed impact on food prices have raised concerns amongst stakeholders and policymakers about the functioning of the food supply chain. The European Commission has launched policy initiatives for the food supply chain in order to promote sustainable and market based relationships between stakeholders of the food supply chain and to increase transparency along the chain to spur competition and improve resilience to price volatility

    A piacok szerepe és lehetőségei a hazai élelmiszer-ellátási láncban

    No full text
    A rövid ellátási láncok egyik speciális esete a piaci értékesítés, amely a magyar kiskereskedelem területén folytatott kutatások egy méltánytalanul „elhanyagolt” szegmense. Az elmúlt két évtizedben a piacok jelentősége és szerepe a kiskereskedelmen belül a hiper-, szupermarketek és élelmiszerláncok térnyerése mellett, illetve részben ennek következtében csökkent. Ezen a folyamaton nem változtatott, hogy a piacok által közvetíthető értékek egyszerre lehetnek gazdaságiak, társadalmiak, valamint környezetiek. A megváltozott kiskereskedelmi környezet miatt a piacok működtetésének eddigi stratégiái már nem garantálják azok sikeres fennmaradását, ezért az üzemeltetés innovatív módszereinek alkalmazása szükséges a már meglévő, valamint az újonnan létesítendő piacok tervezéséhez is. A kutatás eredményei szerint összességében a termelők és a fogyasztók nagyon hasonlóan ítélik meg a piacok jellemzőit, azonban a termelők minden területen jobbnak értékelték a piaci értékesítést, mint a fogyasztók. Ebből arra következtethetünk, hogy a piac eladói túlértékelik saját helyzetüket, a közvetlen kapcsolat ellenére sem teljesen reális a képük a fogyasztói igényekről, ami a vásárlóerő további apadásával járhat. Emellett az üzemeltetők zöme semmiféle eszközt nem alkalmaz azon célból, hogy megfelelően tájékoztassa a vásárlókat a piac árusairól és termékeiről, illetve a piac egészéről, ami elengedhetetlen a piacok iránti fogyasztói bizalom és a forgalom növeléséhez. ------------------------------------------------------- Markets are a special kind of short supply chain and it is an unfairly ‘neglected’ aspect of Hungarian retail trade research. In the past two decades the presence and role of markets in the retail sector has decreased as the hyper/supermarket and discounter retail chains have expanded. This decline was not infl uenced by the fact that markets may provide economic, social and environmental benefits at the same time. Because of the drastically changed retail environment the previous operational strategies do not guarantee the survival of the existing markets, thus innovative management methods must be implemented for the existing and newly founded markets to succeed. Our research has shown that overall farmers and buyers evaluated markets quite similarly but in every question vendors had a more favourable opinion about markets than consumers did. This suggests that, despite their direct relationship with consumers, market vendors overestimate customer satisfaction, which in the long run may negatively infl uence the position of the markets. In addition – according to the consumers and producers – the markets rarely provide effective information and marketing strategies about the producers, the products or the market itself, which would be essential for increasing both consumer trust and footfalls in markets

    Sobre la concepción de la muerte en la filosofía de Nietzsche

    No full text
    This paper deals with the problem of death in Nietzsche's thought. In his program concerning the revaluation of all values death plays a fundamental role. First the author analyzes Nietzsche's critical attitude towards death in connection with Socrates and St. Paul who were the founders of the so-called «metaphysical concept» of death in the European culture. After it the author tries to outline the positive doctrine of Nietzsche's view on death. The final conclusion is that death is, in the last analysis, a hermeneutical question in Nietzsche's philosophy.El presente trabajo trata del problema de la muerte en el pensamiento de Nietzsche. En su programa con respecto a la transvaloración de todos los valores de la muerte desempeña un papel fundamental. Primero, se analiza la actitud crítica de Nietzsche a propósito de la muerte en relación de Sócrates y San Pablo que fueron los fundadores del llamado «concepto metafísico de la muerte» en la cultura europea. Después se intenta esbozar la doctrina positiva de Nietzsche sobre la muerte. La conclusión final es que la muerte es, a fin de cuentas, una pregunta hermenéutica en la filosofía de Nietzsche

    Concentration in Hungarian Food Retailing and Supplier-Retailer Relationships

    No full text
    The paper is a summary about the Hungarian retail sector based on the results of different research projects completed in the last five years. From all of these studies and of course the wide ranging domestic and international literature we had to conclude that the retailers have become more and more the exclusive owner of the information about the consumers and with this they become the new "captains" of the food chain. Thus we always started our research with gathering information about the situation of the Hungarian retail sector because we believed if we want to help those who try to adapt (the suppliers) then we have to know much more about those who dictate (the retailers). Analysing the concentration in company and not branch level we can say that the cumulated concentration line of the CR-10 companies are very similar to that of the processing and the retail sector. But there is a very important difference in the absolute numbers. This is a further sign of the size and power difference in favour of retailing

    Magyarország élelmiszer-gazdasági export-versenyképességének elemzése

    No full text
    Magyarország élelmiszer-gazdasági exportja dinamikusan emelkedett az utóbbi évtized-ben, azonban a konstans piaci részesedés (CM S) elemzés szerint szinte kivétel nélkül a piaci nagyság növekedése hozta az exportbővülést. A piaci összetételhatás a vizsgált országokban többnyire pozitív, de kis értékű, míg a versenyhatás jelentősen negatív volt, vagyis a magyar kivitel kevésbé tudott alkalmazkodni a célpiacok keresletének változásához. A magyar agrárkivitel alakulása a vizsgált időszakban sikeresnek tekinthető Olaszország és Szlovákia esetében, ahová a piaci növekedés ütemén felül bővítettük kivitelünket. A keres-let növekedésétől, azaz a lehetőségektől elmaradó exportváltozást mértünk viszont Lengyelor-szág és Oroszország esetében, ahol a gyengülő versenyképesség gyakorlatilag megfelezte a piaci nagyság és a piaci összetétel hatásából adódó potenciális kivitelnövekményt. Az ár- és minőségi versenyképességet elemző számítások azt igazolták, hogy inkább a relatív olcsóbb termékek tudtak piaci pozícióikon javítani: a német piacon ez a repcemagra és a kukoricára, az olasz piacon pedig a búzára és a kukoricára volt igaz. A megvizsgált húster-mékek ezzel szemben átlagos árfekvést és stabil piaci pozíciót mutattak a német és az olasz piacokon. ----------------------------------------------------- The Hungarian agri-food sector export has grown dynamically over the last decade. We used constant market share (CMS) analysis to decompose the changes in export growth into components. Almost without exception, the increasing market size provided the majority of export growth. The commodity (composition) and competitiveness effect components had varied results and were not so positive. They showed that the Hungarian export structure was less adaptive to demand changes in the target export markets. There were positive examples of export growth however, such as Italy and Slovakia, where the competitiveness effect explained more than half of the Hungarian exports. The neg-ative examples are numerous; the most important are the Polish and Italian trade relationships where competitiveness effectiveness almost halved the measured export growth potential. By analysing the price and quality competitiveness with relative unit value (RUV) cal-culations we could show that in the case of the cereal and oilseed commodities the relatively lower-priced products could improve their market position. In the case of the German market Hungarian rapeseed and maize gained market share with relatively low prices, and on the Ital-ian market this was true for wheat and maize. The analysed meat products on the other hand could only secure a stable market position with their average prices on the German and Italian markets
    corecore